Reflections of an Institutional Economist: Charles Whalen, Part III
This is the third of a four-part series in which the author
reflects on four decades of studying and working in the institutionalist
tradition of economics. Dr. Charles Whalen is a
visiting scholar at the Baldy Center for Law and Social Policy, University at
Buffalo, and served as the 2018 president of the Association for Evolutionary Economics, an
international organization for economists and other social scientists seeking
to advance the institutionalist tradition. Whalen's
remarks
are summarized in four parts: Beginnings; The Nature of Institutional Economics; John R. Commons’s Continuing Relevance; and Assessing the Economy, and will be released each Monday from February 10th to March
2nd, 2020.
Reflections of an Institutional Economist
Charles Whalen[1]
Part
III. Reclaiming the “Right to Work” as a Progressive Cause:
John R. Commons’s Continuing Relevance
Today in the United States, a number of members of Congress —
including some running for President — support proposals that would establish a
job guarantee for all Americans seeking work. Much of the research providing
intellectual support for such proposals comes from economists writing in the
1980s about the need for government to serve as an “employer of last resort.”[2]
However, arguments for that policy idea can be traced back
much further: John R. Commons, a founding contributor to institutional
economics, wrote in favor of government jobs for the unemployed as
early as the 1890s. Back
then, the “right to work” was a progressive cause, aimed at providing jobs for
the unemployed; not until the 1940s did it become associated with anti-union
legislation. This blog post illustrates Commons’s continuing relevance by
reviewing his argument on government’s role in ensuring jobs for people who are
out of work.[3]
In a series of works published between 1893 and 1900, Commons
presented the right to work as a logical extension of the right to life and
liberty, each of which, he argued, must be secured by government.[4] Drawing on those works,
Commons’s argument can be outlined as follows.
First, the right to liberty is not a single right. Rather, it’s
“a bundle of rights,” which grants us freedom to do many things, including
contract with others, leave one employer and work for another, and establish a
new enterprise. The bundle evolves over time, as society recognizes that
conditions have changed.
Second, economic conditions in the United States changed considerably
during the second half of the 19th century. In particular, Commons argued it
was no longer possible for many wage earners to acquire the land, equipment,
and financial resources needed to establish a farm or business. Land had become
scarce; industrialization made expensive machinery necessary for production;
and monopolies made it difficult for modest operations to compete. As a result,
wage labor was often the only route to providing for one’s self and family.
Third, the new economic conditions of the late 19th century
threatened the right to life and liberty—not only by limiting people’s options,
but also by increasing the element of coercion in the employment relationship.
When it comes to hiring, and bargaining over wages and other conditions of
employment, employers can use persuasion, but they also benefit from a worker’s
fear of deprivation. And, since most workers in the 1890s had no option but
wage labor, employees were in a weak bargaining position.
As a result, Commons concluded that
the “bundle of rights” must be updated to contain the right to work. That right
would be defined and enforced by a web of laws aimed at unemployment
prevention, unemployment compensation, and public employment. Taken as a whole,
Commons saw this web as “the next great human right.”[5]
On the matter of public employment, Commons called for
providing the unemployed with the right “to have work furnished by the
government.”[6] The thrust of this
recommendation was aimed at the loss of employment caused by business-cycle
downturns, but Commons also suggested that public employment would be needed to
help some displaced workers at all business-cycle stages. In addition, he saw such employment
as a wage policy as well as an employment policy: “The right to employment
would give laborers steady work throughout the year, and ... abolish
involuntary poverty among the able-bodied.”[7]
To summarize: the “bundle of rights” that Commons envisioned
would expand the liberty of working people—by reducing coercion and capricious
use of power in employment relations, by increasing employment security and
economic security, by providing new economic opportunities, and by bolstering
incomes. In short, furnishing work for the unemployed was part of his overall
aim to “save capitalism by making it good.”[8]
Sometime ago, John Kenneth Galbraith argued that the New Deal
was deeply conservative, “because it was intended to preserve the social
tranquility and sense of belonging without which capitalism could not have
survived—and still will not survive.”[9]
In my view, so it is today with the right to work. In fact, today’s challenge
is not merely to preserve social tranquility, but also to avert an irreversible
ecological crisis triggered by global warming.[10]
A job guarantee isn’t a cure-all. Still, such a
policy—especially if accompanied by healthcare and other employee
benefits—could be of great help to individuals and communities even in the
current period, when the official rate of unemployment is low. Besides, it’s
better to put the public-service employment machinery into place during a
period of low unemployment—a point that Commons and colleagues made in a 1925
book on preventing and coping with unemployment, which he saw as “the
outstanding defect of capitalism.”[11]
The bottom line: the right to work can be reclaimed as a
progressive cause—and even Common’s earliest writings remain relevant to our
economic challenges and policy discussions.
[1] The author is a
visiting scholar in the Baldy Center for Law and Social Policy, University at
Buffalo. These remarks were originally prepared for a two-day exploration of
institutional economics, convened at Michigan State University, May 16-17,
2019.
[2] See, for example,
Hyman P. Minsky, Stabilizing an Unstable Economy (New Haven: Yale
University Press, 1986), pp. 308-313.
[3] Over the course of
his career, Commons actually produced three arguments favoring government as
employer of last resort. The argument here, which was the first to appear in
his writings, is what I call the “legal” case for the right to work. Later in
his career, Commons also offered “financial” and “historical” arguments. For a
more detailed discussion of Common’s legal argument, see Charles J. Whalen, “Institutional
Economics and Chock-Full Employment: Reclaiming the “Right to Work as a
Cornerstone of Progressive Capitalism,” Journal of Economic Issues (June
2019), pp. 321-340. The other arguments are outlined in Charles J. Whalen, “John
R. Commons and Government as Employer of Last Resort: Three Paths to a Progressive
Right to Work,” presented on January 4, 2020, at the annual meeting of the
Association for Evolutionary Economics, in San Diego, California.
[4] See the following
by Commons: The Distribution of Wealth (New York: Macmillan and Company,
1893); “The Right to Work,” The Arena 21: 2 (1899), pp. 131–142; and “A
Sociological View of Sovereignty, Part VI,” American Journal of Sociology
5: 6 (1900), pp. 814–825.
[5] Commons, The
Distribution of Wealth, pp. 80-81.
[6] Commons, The
Distribution of Wealth, p. 81.
[7] Commons, “The
Right to Work,” p. 141.
[8] John R. Commons, Myself
(New York: Macmillan, 1934), p. 143.
[9] John Kenneth
Galbraith, “Franklin D. Roosevelt Recalled as a ‘Superbly Practical Man’.” The
Boston Globe March 4, 1983, p. 2.
[10] For a discussion
of the role that a progressive right to work could play in addressing today’s
economic, social, and environmental challenges, see Whalen, “Institutional
Economics and Chock-Full Employment,” cited above. While economic conditions
have certainly continued to evolve since Commons wrote on the need for an
updated bundle of rights, joblessness—the threat of it as well as the reality—remains
among the most serous of all labor problems.
[11] Lewisohn, Sam A,
Ernest G. Draper, John R. Commons, and Don D. Lescohier. 1925. Can
Business Prevent
Unemployment? (New York: Alfred A
Knopf, 1925), p. 52.
Comments
Post a Comment